« Alito and Legislative History | Main | Kahan on Goldsmith and Yoo »

Tuesday, June 06, 2006

Panel Shopping and Voluntary Mooting: A Problem Worth a Solution?

I've been thinking a lot lately about the government's successful mooting of the "enemy combatant" phase of the Jose Padilla case, at least partially because of the recent developments in the case deftly summarized by my colleague Michael Froomkin over at Discourse.net here and here.

To whatever extent the shenanigans in Padilla (and Judge Luttig's angry opinion in response) brought some broader attention to the problem of voluntary mooting on appeal, however, the attention was focused on the Supreme Court and the last possible stage of litigation.

But voluntary mooting happens with far greater frequency in the courts of appeals, especially once the composition of the panel is publicly disclosed (admittedly, not so much an issue in the Supreme Court). Howard Bashman has elsewhere documented the differences among the circuits with respect to when a panel's identity is released, but they are all released at some point. And as most current and former appellate law clerks can attest, last-minute requests to remand to the district court or the administrative agency, to approve settlements, or to otherwise dispose of the appeal in some manner not affecting the merits are hardly unusual in the 24-48 hours after the panel's composition is made public. From my own experience on the Ninth, we would see such requests all the time in immigration cases...

For litigants in a position where individual cases are less important than systematic legal rules, e.g., the government, groups like the Sierra Club in environmental cases, etc., there is an obvious advantage in preventing "bad" panels on the courts of appeals from reaching the merits when another case might allow a "better" panel to decide the same legal question. But should such blatant "judge-shopping" be tolerated? If not, what can be done about it?

For sure, these are two very distinct questions.

I don't want to dwell too long here on the first question, because I imagine there are fairly divergent views out there (and hope readers will use the Comments to share their own thoughts). My own view, though, is that panel-shopping dangerously undermines the randomness of appellate panels in the Courts of Appeals. What makes the circuits great is that different panels on the same court can answer the same question in two (or dare I say, six) different ways.

Moreover, panel-shopping would give institutional litigants, no matter which side they're on, a huge advantage over non-institutional litigants, e.g., petitioners in immigraton cases; prisoners in habeas cases; etc. By allowing those litigants to seek out panels likely to be receptive to their position, panel-shopping would only serve to distort the law within individual circuits, and, quite possibly, to force circuits to take more cases en banc where particularly unrepresentative panels are consistently deciding specific legal issues in a manner inconsistent with a majority of the circuit.

The harder question, it seems to me, is whether anything can be done to alleviate the "problem." Changing the timing of the release of the panel's identity doesn't strike me as a solution, because the panel would still become public at _some_ point, and it's at that point that the panel-shopping concerns would become manifest.  I also agree with Howard, who argues in his law.com column that advance disclosure is preferable to day-of notification.

An alternative possibility would be a new Federal Rule of Appellate Procedure, which would require judicial approval of any attempt to do away with an appeal after the identity of the panel is released (such approval is already required, but there's no standard that governs, and as Padilla demonstrates, it's often the case that the result is compelled when one party moots the appeal). The pressure on appellate judges to reduce their overbearing caseload where possible might well undermine that idea, unless the rule barred such voluntary mooting absent a change in the underlying facts, and even then imposed a strong presumption against dismissing the appeal.

I'm not sure that would work, either, but it's at least a starting point... As I preach to my Civil Procedure class, it's often more important for the Rules to protect the proverbial little guy, and this is another such example.

Posted by Steve Vladeck on June 6, 2006 at 01:18 AM in Law and Politics, Steve Vladeck | Permalink

TrackBack

TrackBack URL for this entry:
https://www.typepad.com/services/trackback/6a00d8341c6a7953ef00d834c8549f69e2

Listed below are links to weblogs that reference Panel Shopping and Voluntary Mooting: A Problem Worth a Solution?:

Comments

You go Prof! Stick it to the man!!

Posted by: wpbeardsley | Jun 8, 2006 4:15:17 PM

It seems to me that the problem of panel shopping is considerably worse than the problems of fact shopping and argument tailoring. Courts, if they do their job very well, can solve the latter two problems. Judges can avoid or limit the problem of fact shopping by exercising a modicum of judicial modesty, deciding cases with extreme facts narrowly; similarly, they can limit the problem of argument tailoring by noting that the one-time player has no incentive to make big picture arguments and going out of their way to thinking about those arguments anyway. (I suppose that solution is limited if the one-time player waives a claim entirely, but my instinct is that argument tailoring will occur more often vis-a-vis how an argument is made rather than whether it is made.) On the other hand, no individual judge, no matter how conscientious or clever, can eliminate the ill effects of panel shopping.

Restrictions on voluntary mooting seem like fairly strong medicine, though. Are there really so many questions of this form (repeat player versus one-time player, recurring legal issue, significant intra-court spread of opinion) that en banc decsions can't solve the problem?

Regarding the Padilla analogy, it seems like part of the reason the government was so interested in mooting the case was because it wanted to preserve the Fourth Circuit's favorable precedent. Had the government gotten its way, that precedent would have bound all courts in one circuit and been strongly persuasive authority (especially considering the esteemed status of its author) in the other circuits going forward. A single district court opinion won't have that forward-looking value as authority, so there is less (I would venture to say almost no) incentive for a repeat player to moot a case simply to try to preserve a positive district court precedent. Consequently, for the most part panel shopping is probably limited to cases in which the repeat player wants to control the circuit precedent, a much more speculative enterprise and therefore unlikely to be done unless the same legal issue is likely to arise quite frequently.

Finally, the exchange regarding "protecting the proverbial little guy" reminds me of the theoretical side of the debate over affirmative action, grounded in a different set of empirical facts. Would a particular rule create bias favoring the one-time player, or would it correct inherent bias favoring the repeat player?

Posted by: Jay | Jun 8, 2006 12:36:01 AM

Is this really any different than the power repeat players have all the time to adapt their strategy in individual cases to their desired systematic rules? Repeat players have the option to decide whether or not to appeal based on facts of the particular case; likelihood of success; risk; etc in a way one-shot players don't. Even within cases, repeat players craft their arguments with an eye toward the big picture more than the individual plaintiff or defendant. I understand why all of this is potentially a problem as a normative matter, but absent some sort of mandatory appeals, I'm not sure how you'd stop it. And I'm not sure how the problem you discuss is any worse. Am I missing something?

Posted by: jenn | Jun 6, 2006 6:08:06 PM

Kate: Fair enough. I agree with you that it's incorrect as a descriptive matter. Where I gather you and I part company is your assertion that it's a bad idea as a normative matter, but we'll save that for another day... :-)

Posted by: Steve Vladeck | Jun 6, 2006 3:30:26 PM

Steve: I agree that panel-shopping by anyone is a bad thing and should be stopped. I just didn’t understand your point about the Rules’ special concern with the little guy. This strikes me as incorrect as a descriptive matter and a bad idea as a normative matter.

Posted by: Kate Litvak | Jun 6, 2006 2:57:25 PM

If I could amend my previsious submission: I agree that a panel would less inclined to DENY an unopposed motion to dismiss.

Posted by: Circuit Clerk | Jun 6, 2006 2:05:27 PM

I agree with the suggestion implicit in your question -- that a panel would be less inclined to grant an unopposed motion to dismiss, particularly where the parties have decided to settle their dispute. I am less troubled by such a tack, on the part of the parties, however, because they are simply assessing the likelihood of success based on the panel that they drew randomly. At the trial level, parties often enter settlement negotiations after they have a hint at the court's view of their case, whether following a motion to dismiss or for summary judgment. It is another matter, however, to seek an adjournment of argument so that an appeal can be decided by a different panel simply because one of the parties didn't like the composition of the first panel.

I think we can all agree that the most troubling aspect of panel shopping is where the parties manipulate the system so as to get an adjudication by, what they view as, a more favorable panel.

Posted by: Circuit Clerk | Jun 6, 2006 2:01:26 PM

Circuit Clerk -- Thanks for your thoughts; I wonder, though, whether the panel is always in a position _to_ deny such motions. For example, if the prevailing party below voluntarily moots a case only _once_ the panel's identity is disclosed, would the panel really be in a position to deny an unopposed motion to dismiss?

Posted by: Steve Vladeck | Jun 6, 2006 1:38:23 PM

As a law clerk to an appellate judge on circuit that has adopted the policy of some advanced notification of panel composition, I am quite familiar with last minute attempts to adjourn an appeal. The practice on the circuit on which I clerk, however, is to deny these motions, absent exceptional circumstances. By the time a case is calendered, the judges and their clerks have spent a significant amount of time preparing for oral argument. The judges are reluctant to squander that time by routinely granting motions to adjourn; it would, in essence, double their workload by requiring them to prepare for cases in which they would not ultimately decide the appeal and prepare for those cases where a prior panel granted a motion to adjourn.

The clerk's office permits parties to notify the court of scheduling conflicts well in advance of argument, but before the panel information is disclosed. Thus, the parties have an opportunity to find an amenable date, for scheduling purposes, but at the time that they are entitled to submit their scheduling conflicts, they lack information about the panel's composition. I think this provides for both the needs of the litigants to find a convenient date upon which to make their arguments and desire of the court to prevent panel shopping.

Posted by: Circuit Clerk | Jun 6, 2006 1:12:37 PM

One obvious solution is for panels to deny last-minute motions to adjourn. I wonder, though, whether the real problem is with repeat players choosing their panels, or choosing their facts. The government can usually pick and choose which cases it wants appealed. If it chooses wisely, it has a pretty good chance of winning before any panel (at least outside the Ninth Circuit :))

Posted by: AF | Jun 6, 2006 11:20:23 AM

As what appears to be usual, you are trying to distort my argument rather than engage it on the merits. My proposal, regardless of what you call it, is for a rule that prevents parties from taking advantage of their status as repeat players to panel-shop. Such a rule, by the way, would equally prevent the little guy from panel-shopping; I would imagine, though, that s/he is less able to under current circumstances.

So, _how_ would such a rule would be giving that little guy "preferential treatment"?

Posted by: Steve Vladeck | Jun 6, 2006 4:57:10 AM

Right, you didn't say anything about "procedural preferences." You said that it should be "more important" for the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure to protect the little guy than to protect the repeat player. I hastily assumed that your proposal of preferential treatment of little guys under the FRCP had to do with procedural preferences. But who knows -- maybe you meant to add a farm subsidy into the FRCP instead. Or a clause about the right to have a date for a senior prom.

Posted by: Kate Litvak | Jun 6, 2006 3:12:07 AM

I don't recall saying anything about "procedural preferences." That's your term, Kate. Rather, the Rules should not allow repeat players to unfairly game the system at the expense of uncommon litigants.

As for the Animal Farm reference, does that make me Snowball?

Posted by: Steve Vladeck | Jun 6, 2006 2:50:20 AM

Is this the chapter of Animal Farm that I missed? Giving procedural preferences to a particular group of litigants means equal protection?

Posted by: Kate Litvak | Jun 6, 2006 2:40:55 AM

More important than to protect the repeat player who already has a decided advantage when it comes to litigation costs, familiarity with the bench, draconian procedural requirements, etc.

That is, it's through the protection of the little guys that the Rules ensure equal treatment under the law.

Posted by: Steve Vladeck | Jun 6, 2006 2:16:05 AM

As I preach to my Civil Procedure class, it's often more important for the Rules to protect the proverbial little guy

It's more important than what? Consistency? Administrability? Equal treatment under the law?

Posted by: Kate Litvak | Jun 6, 2006 1:56:09 AM

The comments to this entry are closed.